Pubdate: Sat, 1 Sep 2001 Source: Social Research (NY) Copyright: 2001, New School University Contact: http://www.mapinc.org/media/1606 Website: http://www.socres.org Author: David Boyum Bookmark: http://www.mapinc.org/decrim.htm (Decrim/Legalization) Note: The author is a public policy consultant in New York City. PROHIBITION AND LEGALIZATION: BEYOND THE FALSE DICHOTOMY Intoxication and addiction weaken self-control, which leads some drug users to engage in damaging behavior-behavior that would not occur but for their drug use. Government efforts to restrict drug use swell public budgets, restrict liberty, and encourage black markets. So both drugs and drug policy can be harmful to the public good. To my mind, that makes drug policy an optimization problem. The goal is to find a drug policy that maximizes the difference between the benefits of reduced use and the various costs of achieving that reduction. Drug policy is not currently formulated with this purpose in mind. One reason is that the goal is not universally accepted. Some, based on libertarian grounds, believe that drugs should be legalized regardless of the resulting costs and benefits. Others agree that cost-benefit considerations are inappropriate, but for a different reason. In their view, drug use is simply wrong. It is surely the case that those who hold these opposing views receive disproportionate airtime in debates over drug policy. Uncomplicated positions are always an easier sell, especially when people are hungry for a "solution" to an intractable problem. Those who view drug policy as a complicated balancing act face a much tougher sales job. Partly as a result of the exposure given to legalizers and drug warriors, drug policy is often seen as a singular choice between prohibition and legalization. This is a classic false dichotomy. No sharp line distinguishes prohibition from decriminalization or regulation (which is what legalization advocates say they are for). All approaches limit the legal access to drugs, and the practical implementation of any scheme is far more important than its nomenclature. Cocaine use is more restricted than marijuana use, but if you looked only at drug listings under the Controlled Substances Act, you might reach the opposite conclusion. Cocaine has a "currently accepted medical use"; marijuana does not. The excessive focus on legalization and prohibition as policy alternatives distracts attention from more pragmatic discussions of drug policy. But drug policy discourse is also hampered by those who consider themselves pragmatists. All too often, self-proclaimed pragmatists are either unaware of or unwilling to admit the drawbacks of the policies they advocate. On one side, those who claim to advocate decriminalization or legalization on cost-benefit grounds rarely acknowledge that making it easier, cheaper, and safer to buy drugs is likely to significantly increase use. Legalizers will not pay attention to me when I challenge their forecasts, but perhaps they will listen to libertarian journalist P. J. O'Rourke, who is sympathetic to their cause: "Then there's the argument that if drugs were legal, the free market would somehow keep people from taking them. Steven Duke and Albert Gross, authors of America's Longest War. Rethinking Our Tragic Crusade Against Drugs, claim that the number of drug bums wouldn't increase, because "the use of heroin and cocaine in a free-market system would adversely affect the quality of the lives of the users." Am I missing something about the current non-free-market system? Is there a special Joy-Popper Visa card that gives me frequent-overdose discounts? Legalizing drugs will lower their price, the more so if price is measured not only in dollars but also in time spent with dangerous maniacs in dark parking lots, not to mention time spent in jail. If drugs turn out to be a case study showing that price has no connection to demand, every economics textbook will have to be rewritten. This will be an enormous bother-if all the economists are stoned (O'Rourke, 2000: 37)." Drug warriors who assert that their hawkish stance is pragmatic, not ideological, suffer from a different kind of denial. They will not accept that because drug dealers who exit the trade are easily replaced, imprisoning drug dealers has little effect on the supply of drugs. Like legalizers, drug warriors probably will not listen to me when I criticize their analytical thinking, but perhaps they will consider what recent Bush appointee and crime scholar John Dilulio has to say. Writing with colleague Anne Piehl, Dilulio stated that "we believe the best estimate of the incapacitation effect (number of drug sales prevented by incarcerating a drug dealer) is zero" (Piehl and Dilulio, 1995: 245). That suggests that one step toward rationalizing drug policy would be to reduce sentences for drug offenses. Although this would be an important step, it should be noted that such a change might have little effect on total imprisonment. Despite what we often hear, the war on drugs has not been the driving force behind the explosion of prison populations. From 1991 to 1997, the nation's prison population increased by 50 percent, but drug offenders accounted for less than a quarter of that growth (Pastore and Maguire, 2000: table 6.38). (It would be more accurate to say that we have had a war on crime than a war on drugs.) And bear in mind that because most drug dealers commit other offenses, a reduction in drug incarcerations will tend to lead to an increase in incarcerations for non-drug offenses. In any case, it is better to incarcerate a drug dealer-cum-robber on robbery charges than on drug charges. The case for imprisoning robbers is more compelling than the case for imprisoning drug dealers. While efforts to reduce the supply of drugs should be scaled back, efforts to limit demand should be stepped-up. Demand reduction should begin with the recognition that drug use is unequally distributed among users, as are the negative consequences of drug use. The heaviest cocaine and heroin users are responsible for the bulk of consumption, as well as a disproportionate share of income-generating crime. (The RAND Inmate Survey found that the most active 10 percent of offenders accounted for the majority of robberies and burglaries. [Visher, 1986].) These criminally active users must be the primary focus of demand-reduction efforts. Treatment programs are helpful, but as Mark Kleiman explains in his discussion paper, a combination of drug testing and sanctions is likely to be more effective. The most promising approach to reducing drug use among criminally active users is to subject probationers and parolees to regular drug testing, imposing immediate and brief (two-day) incarceration for failed or missed tests. References: O'Rourke, P. J. "My Problem with the War on Drugs." Rolling Stone (January 20, 2000). Pastore, Ann L., and Kathleen Maguire, eds. Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics 1999. Washington, D.C.: Bureau of Justice Statistics, 2000. Piehl, Anne Morrison, and John J. Dilulio. "`Does Prison Pay?' Revisited." Brookings Review 13 (Winter 1995). Visher, Christy A. "The RAND Inmate Survey: A Reanalysis." Criminal Careers and "Career Criminals. "Vol. II. Eds. Alfred Blumstein, Jacqueline Cohen, Jeffrey A. Roth, and Christy A. Visher. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 1986: 161-211. - --- MAP posted-by: Doc-Hawk