Pubdate: Wed, 11 Apr 2007
Source: Observer, The (NY)
Copyright: 2007 The Observer
Contact:  http://observertoday.com/home.asp
Details: http://www.mapinc.org/media/2118
Author: Stephen Kershnar
Note: Stephen Kershnar is a philosophy professor at SUNY Fredonia. 
His column appears every other week.
Bookmark: http://www.mapinc.org/pot.htm (Marijuana)
Bookmark: http://www.mapinc.org/dare.htm (D.A.R.E.)
Bookmark: http://www.mapinc.org/find?159 (Drug Courts)

DRUG PROHIBITION -- LOST LIBERTY, MONEY

As the Iraq War drags into its fifth year, there is a far
more destructive policy that has been going on for decades, drug
prohibition. This prohibition is offensive in at least in part because
of its utter contempt for liberty.

In On Liberty (1859), John Stuart Mill put forth the harm principle
which should be a basic tenet in a free society: state coercion is
permissible only when it is necessary to prevent harm to others.

The idea is that the state shouldn't tell persons how to lead their
lives. It shouldn't mandate what people believe, what religion they
practice, what they eat, etc. This seems to capture why alcohol
prohibition was such a bad idea. It was wrong because it involved a
nanny-state government telling adults what harmless activities they
may and may not engage in. However, unlike drug-nannies, the
alcohol-nannies had some respect for American citizens.

While the Eighteenth Amendment banned sale and production of alcohol,
it didn't ban personal consumption.

Some nanny-types argue that drug use isn't harmless because persons
harm others through impaired driving, stealing to support their habit,
drug-fueled violence, etc. There are a couple things to note about
this argument. First, these activities are already illegal and can be
combated by directly targeting them. In fact, the massive resources
used to track down drugs might end up diverting resources needed to
prevent violent crime.

For example, according to anthropologist Michael P. Ghiglieri, citing
Bureau of Justice Statistics, in the 90's, only about 38% of murderers
were sentenced to prison.

Second, if this argument warrants drug prohibition, it provides an
even stronger case for alcohol probation. It's hard to imagine anyone
who isn't a blood enemy of liberty wanting to criminalize alcohol again.

Third, if we allow the criminal law to protect against externalities,
that is, when one person's conduct imposes costs on others, the state
could mandate jogging, body weight, sexual practices, etc. The harm
principle (when narrowed to focus on direct harm to others) is a
bulwark against such an invasion of liberty.

For example, whether persons should be allowed to engage in gay male
sex shouldn't depend on whether sodomy burdens the state-subsidized
medical system.

Even if drug prohibition didn't involve a dizzying lack of respect for
liberty, it probably doesn't pass a simple cost-benefit analysis.

A corollary to the harm principle is something like the following:
before you restrict liberty, you should have convincing evidence that
the benefits of doing so outweigh the costs.

The incarceration costs are staggering. A little background is helpful
here. In 2005, the U.S. has 2.2 million people in prison.

This gives the U.S. the pride of being the world leader in both per
capita imprisonment and total imprisonment. The U.S. has one quarter
of the world's prisoners. A good deal of the problem is drug
prohibition. Data from a 2005 Bureau of Justice study indicates that
in 2003 roughly 22% of prisoners were there for drug crimes (20% of
state prisoners, 55% of federal ones). Here is a back-of-the-envelope
calculation of the state and federal incarceration costs.

The product of 484,000 prisoners (2005 estimate) and $45,000 per
prisoner (incarceration costs plus lost income - note I made this
number up) is $22 billion per year. The pain-and-suffering cost
brought about when you lock half a million men in cages and separate
them from their friends and families doesn't go into this number
despite the fact that it's huge. There are also massive
law-enforcement costs.

The federal drug control budget in 2006 was $12.5 billion. Since
numerous state and local agencies also spend vast amounts of time and
energy pursuing marijuana and other threats to the free world, one can
imagine that the costs here are considerably greater than my low-end
estimate of $34.5 billion.

Worthy of special contempt is the Drug Abuse Resistance Program (DARE)
program. According to a 1998 study by Professors Ronsenbaum and Hanson
of the University of Illinois at Chicago, DARE has no impact on the
long-term rate of drug use by children who go through it. Other
sources claim that this is the same result found in all major research
into DARE's effectiveness. Despite the lack of evidence for its
effectiveness, in 1996 it was administered in 70% of the nation's
school districts, reaching 25 million students.

That year 44 foreign countries also used it. The costs for this
program include not just wasted taxpayer money but also the lost
education time.

Another significant cost is the shredding of the Constitution in
pursuit of recreational drugs.

The Fourth Amendment prohibits unreasonable searches and seizures and
allows warrants only when there is probable cause. Steven Duke of the
CATO Institute points out that in the context of drug prohibition, the
Constitution has been read to allow police to use the lower
reasonable-suspicion standard to search our bodies.

He notes that the Constitution has also been read to allow police to
search mobile homes, closed containers within cars, and cars without a
warrant. It allows them to search open fields and garbage cans and to
conduct close helicopter surveillance of persons' homes and backyards
without warrant or cause.

In pursuit of drugs, he notes, the Constitution "now" allows people to
be searched in their cars or in airports, trains or buses, and
submitted to questioning and dog sniffs.

Drug prohibition likely decreases the frequency of addiction and some
of the horrible results (violence, theft, and abandonment) that
accompany addiction. At the same time, it eliminates some of the good
times people would have by using drugs.

The same factors are present with alcohol.

In the absence of convincing evidence that the benefits of prohibition
outweigh its costs, it's better to err on the side of liberty.

Locally, the costs are substantial. In Fredonia, the town picks up
part of the costs of a police officer for the DARE program and the
salary of an officer to participate in the Southern Tier Regional Drug
Task Force. There is also a drug court in Dunkirk. On Fredonia's
campus, there are administrative attempts to suspend students for
possession and sale of small amounts of marijuana, although to be fair
these don't always involve a first-campus offense.

There is an unsubstantiated rumor that local police offered to waive a
marijuana arrest if the arrestee participated in drug-sting
operations. If true, someone should be fired.

Like alcohol prohibition, drug prohibition tramples on liberty and
doesn't clearly past the cost-benefit test. Sadly, it's probably here
to stay anyway.
- ---
MAP posted-by: Richard Lake