HTTP/1.0 200 OK Content-Type: text/html Policy Of Prohibition A Failure
Pubdate: Wed, 24 Nov 2004
Source: North Shore News (CN BC)
Copyright: 2004 North Shore News
Contact:  http://www.nsnews.com/
Details: http://www.mapinc.org/media/311
Author: J.B. Paradis
Bookmark: http://www.mapinc.org/opinion.htm (Opinion)

POLICY OF PROHIBITION A FAILURE

I was appointed to the provincial court of British Columbia on Feb. 15, 1975.

I retired on Aug. 13, 2003.

During those 28 years, I presided over at least 1,000 cases, some big, most 
small, involving the possession or sale of illegal drugs.

Bail hearings, trials, guilty pleas, applications to forfeit property - I 
took notes on each one.

And a scan of those notes makes it clear that nothing much has changed: the 
same number of people are still choosing to ingest mood-altering 
substances, the same proportion are addicted and there is the same 
persistent, but increasingly lucrative and efficient system of supply.

Over those years we - citizens, police, judges - lived and worked within 
the orthodoxy that all drugs are inherently evil (except, of course, 
alcohol) and that prohibition and punishment can rid us of them.

How wrong we were.

So wrong, it is distressing to consider the evils we spawned in our 
hopeless attempt to impose criminal sanctions for private choices.

The inclination in humans, other mammals, birds and even some insects to 
seek out mind-altering substances is innate. Leaving aside the substantial 
research on the subject, any observant person can see the enduring 
popularity of everything from coffee and tobacco to alcohol and ecstasy. 
There is, always was and always will be a demand for such substances and, 
therefore, there will always be a supply.

Which is not to suggest that drugs are harmless. In fact, it is their very 
potential for harm that, more than anything else, highlights the abject 
failure of the policy of prohibition. But almost all present-day 
non-medical drugs, properly regulated and taken with care, can provide a 
respite from the toil, strife and illness that life inevitably serves up, 
whether you are a Kurdish goat-herder smoking hashish or a Vancouver school 
teacher sipping a scotch.

We have already conceded that much in our acceptance of alcohol, a serious 
intoxicant we can consume without being criminals but which we recognize as 
dangerous when not consumed in moderation or consumed by those too young to 
deal with its effects.

In the face of that innate desire, prohibition becomes nothing more than an 
irresistible force butting up against an immovable object.

Incredible as it may seem, there are no up-to-date reliable statistics on 
illegal drug use in Canada, although the Canadian Centre on Substance Abuse 
will be releasing this month the results of its first comprehensive survey 
since 1994.

There are two other options available to determine if the policy of 
prohibition has had any impact during its almost century-old lifetime: 
American information and statistics on drug crimes in British Columbia.

The Americans are far more rabid in their approach to drugs so it would be 
reasonable to assume that drug consumption there has fallen. Not so. From 
the mid-1960s to 2002, marijuana and cocaine use among 18- to 25-year-olds 
increased from five per cent to 54 per cent and from one per cent to 15.4 
per cent, respectively.

That growth has taken place not only in the face of the threat of serious 
jail time for possession of even small amounts and "three-strikes" laws, 
but also in spite of draconian laws in a number of states that prohibit the 
drug convict, upon release, from collecting welfare, living in public 
housing, receiving food assistance, obtaining a driver's licence, securing 
student loans or applying for a job with any government department or agency.

The B.C. drug crime rate is no more encouraging to the drug warriors. 
Between 1993 and 2002, the incidence of cannabis and cocaine convictions 
rose 66 per cent and 48 per cent respectively with no significant increase 
in policing and prosecution efforts.

Government has a legitimate role in the regulation of recreational drugs 
because they are potentially poisonous substances. Only the purest 
free-marketer would advocate an unregulated market. The LeDain Report of 
1973, still one of the most careful, thorough, balanced and well-written 
explorations of modern non-medical drug use, contains a sort of 
cost-benefit analysis of the various options for the regulation of drugs. 
It concludes that prohibition is one of the least desirable approaches.

Recognizing that drug use "is too deeply rooted and too pervasive to be 
eliminated entirely," the report identifies four good reasons not to resort 
to prohibition.

First, it creates an illicit market, an irresistible playing field for 
serious criminals.

Furthermore, all those offences that are reported as "drug-related" are 
nothing of the kind. They are prohibition-related. A black market grossly 
inflates the price of drugs, forcing the addict into petty crime to pay for 
his drugs. We never read that an alcoholic has broken into someone's home 
to get what he needs, because he buys his addictive substance in a 
regulated market at a reasonable price. And, except for alcohol (a 
substance at the root of well greater than half of all criminal charges), 
offences committed because of the influence of a drug are as rare as 
asteroid hits.

Second, it inhibits any efforts to seek help or treatment when consumption 
gets out of hand and it constrains the creation of resources for those 
purposes.

Third, it inhibits education about the dangers of drugs. If the law 
prohibits them outright, it is difficult to discuss them, particularly with 
teenagers, in the context of a wise exercise of freedom of choice.

Finally, prohibition places a disproportionate demand on law-enforcement 
resources. By 2001, policing drugs in Canada (just drugs themselves, not 
"drug-related" offences) cost $500 million a year, an amount that 
significantly exceeded the amount, over the same period of time, spent on 
the vilified gun-registry program -and with apparently as little bang for 
the taxpayer's buck.

Add to those unfortunate results the demonizing of citizens whose only sin 
is to become addicted to the wrong drug, as well as the corruption of 
enforcement officials and the erosion of civil liberties that inevitably 
creep into investigation of victimless crimes, and the picture is truly dismal.

But the most telling consequence has been the inevitable unreliability, in 
a black market, of the quality and strength of the product - or its 
outright misidentification - and the resulting threat of serious illness or 
death from overdose, let alone the spread of AIDS and hepatitis from needle 
re-use.

In other words, if the regulation of poisons is a reasonable pursuit of 
government, one which justifies a policy in the first place, prohibition 
has enhanced, not diminished, the poisonous potential of street drugs.

The federal government has said repeatedly over the past two decades that 
misuse of drugs is a health issue. It is past time that it acted 
accordingly, shelved its costly and useless policy of prohibition and 
created a rational structure to deal with all non-medical drug use, the one 
presently in use for alcohol: a system of regulated distribution. At a 
stroke, we would destroy the black market, remove a principal source of 
revenue for organized crime and terrorist groups, free up hundreds of 
millions of dollars now spent on enforcement and corrections, create a new 
source of government revenue - to be devoted to drug treatment and 
education - and greatly reduce the incidence of property crime.

Only two things stand in its way. The first is the Law of Natural Inertia 
of Governing Bodies: if a policy would be bold, socially beneficial and 
fiscally prudent, but risky with the electorate and requiring the overhaul 
of entrenched structures, study it some more. The second is the anticipated 
response from our neighbours to the south.

Neither can justify persisting in such a demonstrable failure.
- ---